Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

There are times when we just don't believe what people try to tell us

We agree that we might be wrong to do so but still:

Johan Rockström, the director of the Potsdam Institute for Climate Impact Research and one of the world’s foremost climate scientists, warned that the 1.5C target was not like other political negotiations, which can be haggled over or compromised on.

“A rise of 1.5C is not an arbitrary number, it is not a political number. It is a planetary boundary,” he told the Guardian in an interview. “Every fraction of a degree more is dangerous.”

We get the very definite impression that some people are using climate change as an excuse rather than a reason. It used to be, for example, that we were all told that 2 degrees was the limit. Only when it became obvious that a capitalist, globalised, free market system could meet that 2 degree target did we start to get the shouting that actually, 1.5 was necessary. For there are those who want to insist that it is the overthrow of capitalism - and markets, globalisation - that must be done.

As George Monbiot says in the same edition of the same newspaper:

Capitalism is killing the planet – it’s time to stop buying into our own destruction

The base understanding is in error. The assumption is being made that capitalism demands growth. Which isn’t the point at all. Humans desire growth in the economy - who doesn’t like being richer? - and capitalism is a good way to get it.

But it’s also wrong in another manner. As the basic economic assumptions behind all the predictions of climate change say (the SRES models) continued economic growth is entirely consistent with the continued health of the planet and also with beating climate change. What’s worse for the argument that capitalism is to blame is that those models with globalised free market capitalism do this better, Horrendous results stem from having a regionalised, non-market, socialised economy (the B2 model).

The reason being that very lust for profit directed by that capitalist and market system. It encourages efficiency, it encourages the use of fewer inputs to gain any specific output. Given that the ecological constraint is those inputs (defining the disposal of wastes correctly as an input as well) then for any given standard of living a capitalist and market system will use fewer inputs. Equally, for any possible set of input limitations a capitalist and market based system will provide a higher standard of living.

We can’t help but think that at least some of what we’re being told here just isn’t true. On the basis that at least some are using climate change as the excuse for their desired socioeconomic system rather than as a rational analysis of the problem or even a reason for a specific response.

This is no doubt cynical of us but then as we’ve said before the only correct question in politics is “Am I being cynical enough?”

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

Just a little more proportional representation and we could have perfect government

King Log does appeal:

Government formation talks in the Netherlands have become the longest on record, 226 days after the 17 March elections delivered a fractured political landscape that made parties more reluctant than ever to compromise.

Dutch government coalitions often take months to form, but this year’s post-election talks have been especially drawn out. For months, parties failed to even move beyond the question of who would be allowed at the negotiation table.

If that proportional representation system could be tweaked just a little more then the negotiations could stretch out until the time of the next election. Perfection, no government could ever actually do anything.

The problem with that being that the aim of democracy is to be able to change who is in power. Without elections changing governments we end up with that permanent state of the bureaucracy, just below the politicians, in charge of everything, forever.

This is one of those problems to which there is no solution, just a series of increasingly - or decreasingly - attractive trade offs. Yes, we grasp the arguments that more PR provides ever greater refinement, granularity, to democratic representation. We also, as here, understand that at a certain level of such PR then an actual change in governance becomes near impossible. The very point of elections being to be able to have a change in governance.

The decision is where to be on the spectrum, elections that are truly representative of all opinion and elections that actually perform a useful function.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

It's as if no one bothers to cross check the numbers

Aditya Chakrabortty tells us, in The Guardian, that the state has been permanently hollowed out by the rigours of austerity:

The basic message of today – the most significant in British policymaking this parliament, setting out the shape of the state and budgets for Whitehall departments for years to come – is that the Tories have now called off their decade-long austerity programme, but they will never reverse it. Beyond the NHS, huge swaths of the public realm are now permanently shrunken.

On the same day The Times tells us that:

Rishi Sunak claimed that the Conservatives are the “real party of public services” as he announced a budget yesterday in which government spending will rise to its highest sustained level since before Margaret Thatcher.

And:

The Office for Budget Responsibility (OBR) said that the overall tax burden would be at its highest level since Clement Attlee’s postwar Labour government of 1945-51 and spending at its highest level since the 1970s.

One of those two claims about the size of the state must be wrong. It being that of Mr. Chakrabortty which is so, of course. There has been some movement around of how much is spent upon which thing, that’s true, but then that’s a necessary process even within a rising budget in order to avoid running out of other peoples’ money.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

Modern theories about government borrowing are just so difficult to understand

Two Guardian pieces which seem to be taking entirely opposite sides of the same point. We suppose we could take that as a welcome diversity of opinion over there but that’s not how they’re presenting it:

Lower income countries spend five times more on debt than coping with the impact of climate change and reducing carbon emissions, according to a leading anti poverty charity.

Figures from Jubilee Debt Campaign show that 34 of the world’s poorest countries are spending $29.4bn (£21.4bn) on debt payments a year compared with $5.4bn (£3.9bn) on measures to reduce the impact of the climate emergency.

If poor countries borrow then this leaves them with an horrendous debt burden that they struggle to service:

In his budget, Rishi Sunak will say the UK needs to cut spending. Don’t believe him

Yes, public debt is high, but the way to bring it down is to invest – starting with the government’s social and climate pledges

If we borrow then it creates the income stream - and more - to service that debt burden.

This is the opposite claim of that first. It’s possible to finesse it into coherence by insisting that we will spend the money sensibly - Hah! - and they do not. But that then calls into question the sense of sending more to those poor countries whether as loans or grants. Why send money to where it will be wasted on things that don’t produce a return? No, we don’t mean some mere financial return to lenders, we mean that sending money to where it produces less value than the starting point is to make us all poorer.

So, there’s the interesting question. Why is it that poor places borrowing leads to unsustainable debt burdens but rich places borrowing leads to paying off the debt?

Our assumption is that it’s just politically convenient - it’s Thursday, isn’t it? - to so insist but perhaps someone can come up with a better piece of argumentation than that.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

They're right you know, people will pay more for high animal welfare standards

The National Farmers Union and others argue that we British not only will but positively gasp over the opportunity to pay more for our food if that means higher animal welfare standards. Thus imports of meats produced to lower standards should be banned - no free trade for you!

He said: “People have got more into provenance and wanting to know where their food comes from. The food scares of the late Eighties, early Nineties like mad cow disease and foot and mouth really woke people up in this country to thinking about what they’re eating. And now people are willing to pay a little bit more for good food. People think ‘I can go to Tesco and buy a chicken for £2.50’ and ask why a shop like mine is selling them for £12.

“Well, if you want a free-range chicken, it’s taken two-to-three times as long to rear it and it’s been fed properly and housed properly and that costs money. We find that people maybe eat a little bit less but they want to eat a little bit better and they are willing to pay for it. You’d go to a shop and buy a top-quality suit because you’re going to a wedding, so why not buy top-quality food when you want something really special or if you value your health.”

The truth being that some people are making very good livings meeting those demands for high standards. But, equally clearly, this is a niche taste, niche suppliers for niche markets.

This being the argument for free markets of course, free of import restrictions and bans. For only when the market is indeed free can each niche be served, the different utilities maximised. Those who actively desire the high standards can currently gain them at their relevant cost. This ability will not disappear with freedom. But with that liberty so also will those worried more about the monetary cost than anything else gain their desires.

That is, it’s the very fact that some Britons desire those high standards, others either do not or don’t particularly, which means we should be having that free trade. Because only when the consumer can make a choice are they both free and also at liberty to maximise their own utility.

After all, those who want to pay £12 for a chicken can. But why should those who prefer £2.50 have to?

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

Markets may take their time but they do work

Part - part - of the idea of asking students to pay for their own degrees was that students would then choose degrees which are worth it to them. It is, if you like, akin to a Pigou Tax. There’s a cost to these things and only if those gaining the benefit are also paying the cost will we have the correct amount of the right type of degrees being taken by the people who will benefit from them.

Thousands of academics from across the UK and abroad have signed an open letter calling on Goldsmiths, University of London, to “halt the decimation” of its English and History departments, after the university became the latest institution to announce job cuts in the humanities.

Goldsmiths has announced 52 compulsory redundancies to tackle “significant financial challenges”, targeting English and History as well as administrative staff. The letter, which currently has more than 2,600 signatures, warns that academics with “deeply rooted” expertise in Black and Queer History and Black literature are among those under threat of redundancy. It accuses university managers of running higher education like “fast fashion” and showing “utter disregard for the integrity of the education they want to sell”.

Well, yes, the point about selling things being that you do better selling what it is that the customers wish to buy:

While applications for subjects such as computer science and maths have been booming, applications to study English have slumped, putting the subject in jeopardy at many institutions.

There are those who value a degree in English. There are those who value one in a STEM subject. By exposing those who take such degrees to the cost of them then we sort through those who do in fact value the thing at at least the cost of its provision.

This is not some aberration of the imposition of student fees, this is the point. Markets work, as with the law they grind small even if they can be a little slow.

Read More
Miles Saltiel Miles Saltiel

Not the way to bet

Boris’s central economic policies are “levelling up“ and “green jobs”, the latter falling out of his ambitions for COP26. Unfortunately they run up against the obstinate truth that since WW2, it has never been wrong to bet against UK manufacturing. As we all know, this has been bad news for the individuals and regions once relying on it. Thus, the relative immiseration of Britain’s north and midlands, not to say the formerly-industrial working-class in general.

Nothing works. In the mid-sixties, Kaldor’s Selective Employment Tax failed to give manufacturing the intended leg-up. For a generation after 1963, the Location of Office Bureau pushed only back and middle-office employment out of London - and often no further than smaller towns in the southeast. Apprenticeships suffer from vanishing repute among middle-class or aspirational parents (would you want your child to have one?) and the blind-eye regulation of provincial banks under Blair and Brown, hoped to bring high-quality service jobs out of London, led the outfits concerned to spearhead Britain’s part in the financial collapse of 2008.

So is it hopeless? Almost certainly so, at least within the timescale of an electoral, business or reproductive cycle. Taking this last first: from a personal point of view, it is a longer-shot gamble than ever, for ambitious parents to bring up their kids as a bet against London, or at least the southeast.

As to public policy, officials are confined to:

- Palliative care, e.g. further rusticating government back-offices; and in the case of Channel Four and BBC News, risking the resilience of business models under threat from new media;

- Artless plans to create provincial tech hubs around Russell Group Universities, bound to fail as private investment which is value-added, i.e. associated with applicable skills and relationships, will hesitate to make excursions beyond the proposed Oxford-Cambridge tech corridor - if it ever happens;

- Gestures, e.g. HS2 if it ever happens. Ballooning costs make the railway unlikely to be extended. This means it is destined to frustrate its promoters’ intentions, by making Birmingham further subaltern to London, rather than goosing up the torpid city-regions of Yorkshire and Lancashire.

This is the context for Boris’s economic policies. He is a natural booster and we have to assume that his heart is in it. After all, he famously claimed to be “Brexitty Hezza”, invoking the great Tory interventionist and troublemaker; we may take it that he is not deaf to pillow-talk, and it may help with the kids who hate him but love greenery.

Unfortunately, nothing in 250 years of modern British economic history suggests that government has a contribution to make in such circumstances. Any money spent on the “levelling up” will be public funds, acceptable only by companies either in extremis or for the most cynical of reasons, e.g. to horde labour. As ever, truly promising businesses will seek out and be able to attract value-added money.

This takes us back to COP26 and the “green jobs” underpinning Boris’s net zero commitments. They suffer from similar problems for him: those with any gumption will see state money as the mark of Cain. In addition, the underlying policy relies upon immature technologies, where the bet is that learning-curve effects will tweak the physics and make the economics come good. If so, any profit-maximising promoter of fruitful developments will be looking for manufacturing facilities which are either overseas or labour-light. The private sector will be more suspicious than ever of government money, for fear that the price will be domestic production that is more labour intensive than industrially sensible.

Boris has made a political gamble, no surprise as he is a gambler. But his climate gamble is far riskier than Blair’s original commitments. These piggy-backed on Britain’s coincident move from coal to gas in power generation, guaranteeing that we could meet Blair’s carbon reduction targets. Boris is making bets of his own: that the tide of opinion will continue to flow green, that a enough unproved technology platforms deliver to keep the lights on and that a British government can do something it has never done: supervise an industrial paradigm shift. It’s not the way to bet.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

The problem with cultural appropriation and public goods

Not that we generally turn to Rod Liddle here:

Everything that is good about us as a species has been enhanced and enriched by cultural appropriation, and you would think that the internationalist left would concur. But instead the left insists that we must all squat inside our respective ghettos, because no exchange between us can ever be quite pristine and equal. It is an absurdity.

While there’s many a truth spoken in jest Liddle’s position as the dyspeptic jester - say, the Jack Dee of the broadsheets - does leave him usually some way from our own interests.

However, here we’ve half of something that has long puzzled us. The varied and opposite claims made about public goods and cultural appropriation.

A public good is, in the economic jargon, something that is non-rivalrous and non-excludable. Once it exists there’s no way to stop someone from using it - excludability - and their use of it doesn’t diminish the supply available to others - rivalry. As the supply is therefore unlimited it’s something very difficult to make a living out of producing in the first place. Knowledge being exactly one of these things - once something is known then other people can also know it without reducing the supply to the originator.

All of this is well known within the hallowed halls of social science and it’s the argument in favour of government subsidy of basic research, the existence of patents and copyrights to produce excludability and so on.

It’s also the argument that we in the rich world should be doing all the spending upon vaccine and drug development, renewables research and design, all these sorts of things, then be giving them away to those poorer. Once the thing has been thought up, invented, designed, then humanity is made richer by it being free to use for all.

Well, OK.

But all of these cultural quirks that we must not appropriate are also public goods. The design of a hat - Liddle mentions the sombrero - or the making of a curry (and do leave aside that the vindaloo is an adaptation of the Portuguese vin d’alho to start with) is something which is done once and can then be enjoyed by all. It’s a public good in that economic sense.

At which point we seem to have the same people, for it is largely the same people who make both arguments, arguing that the drug which costs $1 billion to design and test in the first place should not have excludability created via patent, but the tweak to a recipe that was a few minutes of happenstance must be so protected by social conformity against appropriation.

We can’t help but think that there’s a certain illogicality to that stance. Even, that it has the entire thing wholly backwards. For public goods are lovely things, it is indeed true that their spread advances civilisation. Someone has a good idea, we all copy it, we’re better off. The only restrictions we might want upon this, even then only for some limited time like the effective decade of a drug patent, being to encourage the creation in the first place.

If people do invent these things for free anyway then why would we want to limit their spread?

That is, the ban on cultural appropriation is an insistence upon denying ourselves the public goods created by others. Why would we want to do that?

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

The costs of going green

We’re told that plans to go green will cost some £1.4 trillion:

And it will also cost an eye-watering sum – as much as £1.4 trillion, according to the Climate Change Committee, which advises the Government on its net-zero strategy.

This, very sadly, being an underestimate.

The actual cost of something is whatever must be given up in order to gain it. Which means there are further costs to consider, over and above the mere money:

According to Wells, the shift to electric needs to coincide with significant behavioural change in order to be a success in actually driving down emissions, with far less car ownership. The Government hopes half of all urban journeys will be taken by foot or bicycle by 2030.

“It is a mistake to think we can simply replicate our petrol and diesel fleet in electric and use our cars the way we do now,” he says. “That in itself is a significant policy failure.”

We’re all to have less freedom and mobility.

There are obvious health and societal benefits in eating seasonally, locally and limiting the amount of meat and dairy in our diets.

We’re to return to the diets of medieval peasants - meat to be for high and holy days only.

It has also pledged to introduce a standardised approach where green waste, food waste and tougher-to-recycle plastics – from single-use polyethylene plastic bags to the pump mechanisms in bottled lotion dispensers – will be collected from every home across the country.

We’re all to spend many more hours sorting things for the binmen.

We will be expected to bring an array of empty tubs and cartons to fill up at the supermarket, while high street fashion labels such as H&M are increasingly trialling repair shops where customers can bring in old garments for recycling, rather than merely buying new ones.

The assumption that washing the tupperware uses fewer resources than fresh single use plastic is very dodgy indeed. And don’t you just love that word “merely” about us all going back to wearing patched rags?

Unless new technologies are rapidly advanced, it seems to meet net zero, staycations are here to stay. “The unpalatable truth,” she says, “is we really have to fly less or at least not allow aviation to increase as it has done.”

Do not even think of jetting off to find the Sun.

The costs of going green are very much higher than that £1.4 trillion.

As the Stern Review itself pointed out, humans tend to do less of more expensive things, more of those cheaper. There has to be a concentration upon dealing with climate change the cheap way therefore - because that’s the way we’ll do more of it. Or, as the Review also pointed out, stop damn planning things and get the market prices right and leave well alone afterwards.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

Well, yes Polly, but the NHS still isn't very good

Polly Toynbee tells us that the National Health Service is very green, as health services go:

But one event at Cop26 will raise the spirits. The NHS, far out ahead, will make a key presentation to the world’s other health systems to show what can be done. The NHS is responsible for 5% of the UK’s carbon emissions: the recently departed head of NHS England, Simon Stevens, put climate targets firmly into the NHS long-term plan, warning: “If health services across the world were their own country, they’d be the fifth-largest emitter on the planet.”

You might think going green was the last thing the NHS could do right now, after its decade of unprecedented underfunding, with waiting lists going through the roof, acute doctor and nurse shortages, and burnt-out staff being awarded paltry pay rises. But no. Jackie Daniel, head of Newcastle upon Tyne hospitals, has pioneered the green cause within the NHS and is making the Cop26 presentation to world health services. “A few, exhausted trusts did think this was the last thing they could cope with now,” she tells me. “But astonishingly, nearly everywhere has seized on this. We’ve found it’s something that really enthuses staff, and they have been the ones driving it forward.”

We also know that the NHS is very equitable, most fair and offers equal access to all. All quite possibly desirable attributes of a health care system.

We can’t help but keep reminding ourselves that even with all of this the NHS isn’t in fact a good health care system. As the OECD (and others, there are a number of attempts at quantifying this) points out the NHS just isn’t very good at “mortality amenable to health care”. That is, stopping people from dying from things which medical treatment could stop them dying from. We may indeed be merely neoliberal utilitarians but we do think that could be a significant aim of having a health care system.

Even to the point that worrying a little less about greenery, equity, equality and so on might - just possibly, you know? - lead to an improvement in actually curing patients?

Read More
Your subscription could not be saved. Please try again.
Your subscription has been successful.

Blogs by email