Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

The difficulty of governing a society in any detail

Three little stories from just one issue of one newspaper:

Shell is planning to finally scrap the complicated Anglo-Dutch structure that critics say has been a drag anchor for years.

It would shift the firm’s centre of gravity decisively from The Hague to London, completing a process started in 2005.

The second:

The Church of England is facing questions over its role in converting hundreds of asylum seekers, including the Liverpool suicide bomber, to Christianity in an attempt to help them avoid deportation.

The third:

Female prisoners should not be forced to live with “big, brute rapists who have decided to identify as women”, a former minister has said.

Dutch law places significant barriers to stock repurchases through the dividend tax imposed in that country. Folks can - and do, obviously - get around that simply by leaving.

Apostasy is a crime carrying the death penalty in certain Muslim countries and the end result can be informally applied in some other majority Muslim places. Apostasy as a method of not being sent back to such places can have its attractions.

Rules about gender and prison places can be gamed - so, they are.

Our point is not that any of these rules are incorrect. Nor that there don’t have to be rules in such areas. If there’s corporate taxation then there must be rules about what corporate taxes are. If a distinction is to be made between an asylum seeker and an economic migrant then rules about which is which have to exist. If the prison estate is split along gender (or sex, use whichever word you prefer) lines then rules there have to be over the definition of gender (or sex) suitable for each part of that prison estate.

Our point is that any such rules will be gamed or avoided over time. Simply because that’s what we humans out here do. We look at the rules constricting us and plot our slides through the thickets. This means that any attempt to rule a society in any detail fails.

For once that path that may be slid along is identified, here comes another rule to block it, then another iteration of exploration, another set of rules, avoidance, rule and so on until:

However, it was during his travels that Mr Koenig realised “just what a source of distress it was to our country.”

“These are not just anecdotal tales of paperwork but something much deeper about the way the state is structured. France remains highly Jacobin - very centralised, interventionist and dirigiste,” he said.

“It belies a lack of trust in the individual whose every move is micromanaged. That creates a huge sense of mistrust among citizens against the powers that be and has seen France descend slowly into a sweet anarchy where nobody respects the rules as they are no longer intelligible.”

Yes, of course it’s possible to make cheap jibes about how none of us actually want to become French. But this is the end result of such stultifying rule making - everyone ignores them. One of us spent considerable time in the late Soviet Union and its aftermath and life was lived in the interstices of those all encompassing rules. Just everything was approached from the aspect of well, here are the rules, so we obviously don’t do any of that and how do we slide by them?

The detailed governance of tens of millions of people just isn’t possible because people are, well, they’re people. They’ll game any such system and the greater the clampdowns the more they’ll - we’ll - ignore the rules as a whole.

That is, the old British system of having few specific rules, a few general principles and enforcement only of the important stuff actually does work. To the annoyance of would be rule makers, papershufflers and clipboard wielders everywhere.

That that’s also a description of a free and liberal society is a useful coincidence but it is that, a coincidence. It’s the system that actually works is the point we want to get across here.

Governments need to rule lightly to rule successfully.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

Once more into the breach dear friends - time to sort out low pay again

Polly Toynbee alerts us to one of the unfairnesses in modern life. For once we actually agree with her as well:

On Monday, the “real living wage” – a voluntary scheme – is rose to £9.90 an hour outside London, which equates to £1,930 more a year than the government’s so-called national living wage (NLW).

As we’ve pointed out before there’s nothing wrong with that real living wage calculation, it uses the same underlying logic as Adam Smith and the linen shirt. If the people in a society think that not being able to do - or own - these things makes you poor then in that society, if you can’t, then you’re regarded as being poor.

As we’ve also pointed out, in common with the New York Times back when it knew things, the actual minimum wage is £0. We’re thus not in favour of the idea of a legislated minimum wage any higher than that. It is though true that one exists and that’s the world we currently live in.

At which point to complain about something we’ve shouted about before. Shouted, complained, about to the extent that policy changed.

Back in 2004, 2005, however far back in the mists of time it was, when the Joseph Rowntree folks first started calculating this living wage, we pointed out that the difference between that and the legal minimum wage of the time was near entirely the amount of tax charged to those on low incomes. Every year, as both changed, we made the same calculation and indulged ourselves in making the same point. If we were to lower the taxation of the poor by increasing the personal allowance to that full year, full time, minimum wage then we would have solved the problem being complained about. The post-tax take from the minimum wage, untaxed, would be the same as the living, now real living, wage as taxed.

We wish to increase the incomes of the working poor? Then stop taxing them so damned much.

This became one of those things that took off as a political meme. One of us had significant input into the tax part of a fringe party political manifesto where the idea appeared. Our advocacy here convinced various Lib Dems including a certain Mr. Clegg - aha, aha, to the extent that they’re not or weren’t a fringe political party. The good folks at the Centre for Policy Studies worked on George Osborne and so when the Coalition came together it became policy.

Those decades of fiscal drag that led to part timers on minimum wage paying income tax were reversed. The personal allowance was raised from the £4,000 or so level up to the current £12,570. It took half a decade to get the idea established, a decade following that to get the change fully implemented. That the number is £12,500 plus a little inflation is because that’s what the full year, full time, minimum wage was when the ambition was announced.

And now we’ve all got to do it all over again. For look at Polly’s number there. £1,930 a year. As the minimum wage is currently £8.91 an hour that means the work year is being calculated as 1,950 hours (1930/99p is 1949 an’a’bit) Which looks a little high for the average but isn’t far off that average for full time workers.

OK. So, 1950 hours times that £9.90 is £19,305 for that real living wage. Given that that’s well into the top 10% of global incomes we do think that’s pretty high for a minimum wage but still. The personal allowance for income tax is £12,570. So, 20% income tax is paid on £6,735 a year - £1,347. “Employees’” national insurance starts at £9,568 so the 12% charge is on £9,737 and is £1,168.44. Everything gets worse if we include “employers’” NI which is, as we know, incident upon wages.

So we have this situation where we’re charging £2,515 in tax to those we also insist are only just making it out of poverty for a full year’s work? Further, where we could solve this simply by insisting that the full year, full time, minimum wage is what the personal allowance should be - for both NI and income tax of course.

For look at what happens. The current minimum wage is, for those working hours, £17,374 a year. The current real living wage as currently taxed is £16,790.

We do not, in fact, have wage poverty here, we have tax poverty. The problem is not the wages being paid, it’s the exactions upon them.

Or, as we said all those years ago and won in part - because we were right - and as we’ve got to shout about all over again. If we want the poor to be richer then stop taxing them so damn much.

The only even possibly logically valid argument in favour of a minimum wage - one that, as above, we don’t in fact agree with - is that it’s a moral issue. Society has decided that that’s the minimum, irreducible, value of an hour’s work and that’s that. OK then, that’s the minimum, irreducible, value of an hour’s work then and society doesn’t get dibs on a slice of that in the form of tax.

Both these numbers, the personal allowance (even, three numbers, taking NI and income tax as having different allowances) and the minimum wage are under the control of the Chancellor of the time. One day we’ll have one who does the right thing and makes it clear that they’ve all got to be the same number. The tax allowances are the full year, full time minimum wage, the full year, full time, minimum wage is the tax allowance.

Anything else is building the society on the backs of those we’ve already declared are too poor to fund it and why the hell would we do that?

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

Conglomerates and the financialisation of everything

General Electric is to split itself up into three companies in a continuation of a process that has been going on for decades more generally - that death of the conglomerate. In a description of why they used to exist we have this:

What’s more, the cash generated by one division could be used to fund research and development in another.

We would not say that what is about to follow is the entire explanation but we would insist that it’s part of it.

Raising money used to be an expensive operation. Stock and other capital markets were not that liquid. Spreads were wide. The pool of capital was not that deep.

As those people complaining about the financialisation of everything have been saying, the financial markets are much larger now. They’re distinctly more efficient. Spreads are vastly lower - we’ve seen one estimate that stock spreads in New York have declined by two orders of magnitude in the last few decades. This is, of course, at least partially a result of High Frequency Trading.

The influence upon conglomerates is that it used to be sensible enough to keep money within a company and reinvest it within the corporate envelope. Thus disparate lines of business with the cash flow of one financing the next. This has obvious costs in that a structure, management, workforce, optimised for one task didn’t necessarily have the skills - possibly the gumption, or even a clue - to run that entirely different line of business. But that cost of running finance across the corporate boundary made up for that.

Now that cost of raising finance is much lower. So too is the cost of paying out past profits to shareholders. So the cost of specialisation has come down - and so we see more specialisation.

This is exactly the flip side of all those complaints that companies are paying out profits as dividends, performing stock buybacks and so on, rather than investing internally. We have more efficient financial markets now so paying out the gains from one line of business to leave individual investors with the capital allocation decision now makes more sense than it did.

As we say, we’d not die in a ditch to insist that this is the only thing that has been going on. But we’d certainly deploy those logical shovels to dig in on the point that this is partially to largely true.

The increased efficiency of financial markets has meant that we no longer have to put up with the inherent inefficiencies of conglomerates. Or at least less so that we used to. We take this to be a good thing as we generally do about increased economic efficiency.

Read More
Tim Ambler Tim Ambler

Oh what a tangled web we weave

Some people want to be MPs, MPs want to be ministers and ministers want to be financially comfortable in their later years.  According to Monday’s Guardian, half of all Tory ex-ministers take jobs in companies relevant to their former departments. Business is driven by value for money and directors would not be offering employment for the pleasure of ex-ministers’ company at their lunch tables.  The Patterson affair was trivial: the line between advising on lobbying and helping out with doing it is a fine one, remembering that the companies will make no secret of where their advice came from. The civil servants who actually make the decisions are well used to ignoring the lobbying by their own ministers, never mind other MPs. 

One wonders for example what motivated the Government to put millions into Rolls Royce generation II small nuclear reactors intended for submarines, 20 years or more ago, and disregard the modern generation IV advanced nuclear reactors (costing about the same but producing more electricity) now being progressed by other leading countries.  It would be absurd to believe that future employment had anything to do with it. 

Parliament should not waste its time on trivia, like the Patterson affair, or whether the Prime Minister had the authority to have his official living quarters redecorated, but on the far more insidious forms of corruption, namely ministers and senior civil servants making decisions in their own long term interest and trespassing on the coattails of quangos and regulators that should be independent but are not.  

My streamlining quangos paper last October showed how they could all be abolished: either they are necessary but should not be independent, in which case they should be integrated within their departments, or they are necessary and should be truly independent, in which case they should report to Parliament, not government, or they are unnecessary and should be abolished. Setting up a new quango to address an awkward issue is bad government and expensive for taxpayers. 

The NHS is a classic case in point: it should either be an Executive Agency (part of government) or a Public Corporation (independent of government and reporting to Parliament). The previous Health Secretary considered these options and decided it was more fun to tell the NHS what to do when he felt like it and disclaim all responsibility when he didn’t.  As a “non-departmental public body”, It remains simultaneously independent, and not independent, of government. 

The fact is that neither this, nor any other, UK government will stop meddling in legislative matters that belong to Parliament or using the tangled web of governance to further its own interests.  And the personal interests of ministers do not necessarily coincide with what the country most needs. 

The country is lucky to have many high quality ex-ministers still serving on the back benches.  They should confer with the leaders of opposition parties to discuss what kind of parliamentary commission should review the streamlining of governance and its relationship with Parliament.  Government would obviously whip against any such motion and we would then see which MPs prefer their own personal ambitions to the best interests of the country.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

Decision making on steel - kick that can

Much muttering is going on over what should be done about steel in the UK. The correct answer being nothing. At least, nothing yet.

The tasks of decarbonising the economy and securing supply chains do not come bigger than for the sprawling steel plant in Port Talbot in Wales.

For more than a century it has dominated the town as one of its largest and best-paying employers.

But the plant, one of the UK’s top carbon polluters, will need to find ways to make steel with less carbon dioxide output - eventually cutting it entirely in the race for net zero.

The challenge for loss-making parent Tata Steel UK is who will pay for improvements to achieve this. An inability to find the funds could put local jobs at risk.

It is possible that the UK really does need to be able to make its own virgin steel. So, scrap recycling with electric arc furnaces is fine but not exclusively. It is possible that it doesn’t so arc furnaces only would be fine.

That though isn’t the only question. There is a method - direct reduction - which is low to no carbon. It depends upon green hydrogen to work usefully. If we do get solar to electrolysis cheaply enough then DRI is the solution. If we don’t it ain’t.

So, what do we do now? We wait.

Which is where we really do insist that doing everything now is not cheaper than just waiting and seeing. Even, this is at the heart of why so many dislike the Nordhaus (you know, the Nobel winning manner of dealing with the problem) approach to climate change. This seeming detail:

Within the next 10 years, one of its two blast furnaces will need replacing, offering the opportunity to simultaneously implement a new system - giving time for new skills to be learned.

The Nordhaus approach is to work with the capital cycle. Don’t scrap perfectly usable stuff we’ve already got built. Wait until we need to replace it anyway then make sure that the replacement is the best - in this case least emittive perhaps - available option at that time.

Don’t tear down usable blast furnaces, tear down ones that need replacing anyway. At which point the begging letters for tax funding are easier to deal with because even if subsidy is still required it’ll only be the marginal cost of the new tech, not the total replacement cost. And, of course, we’ll know a great deal more about whether than green H2 is going to work properly or not in just a few years. If it really does - a reasonable guess being yes it will - then no subsidy will be required as it will the technology of choice anyway.

The general screaming and shouting at present is that we’ve got to do everything right now, today, by lunchtime even. The actual answer is that waiting for the capital cycle is correct. Don’t rip down stuff that works, just make sure the replacement, in its time, meets the new standards. Oh, and make that decision when that time comes, when we know which techs actually work at that point.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

Some assertions end up being ludicrous

It’s a standard claim from the intellectually fashionable these days that “excessive wealth” is the major problem our society, our world, faces. Which leads to statements like this:

We need to redefine what the good life is, instead of never-ending expansion, the latest iPhone, jetsetting. The planet can’t take another Jeff Bezos.

Mr. Bezos has that $190 billion or whatever it is this morning as the stock markets gyrate. But that he has that much is the least important part of the story. How did he get it?

According to the bank, Amazon and its peers have pushed down inflation by about 0.1 to 0.2 percent.

That’s per year for a couple of decades. Certainly, we shouldn’t apply all of that to Amazon, or Bezos, but just for kicks let’s try it. That’s a 4% (without compounding) reduction in the price level. That’s something we consumers gain each and every year. Limit ourselves just to the US economy of $20 trillion - and yes, this is the inflation level for the whole economy, it’s not just on whatever tchotchke Amazon sells - and that’s $800 billion a year. We get $800 a year collectively, he gets $190 just the once. If we capitalise our benefit as that Bezos pile is capitalised then we’re getting $16 to $24 trillion (roughly, you understand) over time.

We’re on the right end of the greatest bargain in all history that is. More formal proof is in this from William Nordhaus.

That things can be provided more cheaply means that we’ve had an increase in efficiency. Which is that we’re using fewer resources to reach a particular standard of living - that’s what an increase in efficiency is. Quite why the planet won’t survive increasing efficiency is something that intellectual fashion doesn’t seem to address. The idea that Gaia will suffer from our using fewer resources seems more than a little odd.

Actually, it’s ludicrous. But then that’s the thing with fashion, the results of the usual groupthink often are ludicrous as catwalks and Guardian columns so often show.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

The capitalist and free market gloriousness of Johnson Matthey's failure

Johnson Matthey has decided to pull out of that so very important battery design business:

Johnson Matthey is to abandon years of research and development and hundreds of millions of pounds spent trying to find the key that will unlock the full potential of electric cars: being able to travel hundreds of miles on a single battery charge, without the weight and cost of batteries that make the vehicle undriveable or commercially unviable.

What joy. For our task is to have a system which explores the technologically available space for manners of sating consumer demands. To sort through what can be done and match that up with what people want to be done. That being what capitalist free marketry does better than any other system we’ve tried as yet.

That this isn’t working out in this instance is a pain for those who funded it, certainly. But the reason for the abandonment?

With the demand for electric car batteries escalating, MacLeod had to admit that Johnson Matthey had lost the technological battery race with producers in low-cost economies such as LG Chem, of South Korea, and CATL, of China.

“While the testing of our eLNO battery materials with customers is going well, the marketplace is rapidly evolving, with increasing commoditisation and lower returns,” he said. “We have concluded that we will not achieve the returns necessary to justify further investment.”

Someone else got there faster, better, cheaper. So, in order not to run out of their money - or their investors’ money - Johnson Matthey stopped. That’s the grand joy, the manner in which the system stops mistakes. It is not just that the envelope is explored, but that when the corners are found it stops.

Just think it through for a moment. The only alternative to folks risking their own money is that government does it for us all. Which is where the big problem arises - government never does stop such things until they run out of other peoples’ money.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

We can also add that the Green New Deal won't actually work

Aditya Chakrabortty rather shocks contemporary opinion by stating that the Green New Deal probably isn’t quite the way to do it:

At some point, the post-2016 left, radicalised by Trump and Brexit, will have to surrender its notions of a radical programme executed through a vast state machinery. …(…)… I hope what comes next is a more focused, locally rooted and inclusive politics based around asking people what they actually need in their lives, and working out how to fit those things within an environmental framework. That can be done with universal desires such as housing and food, healthcare and education.

Indeed so, the task is how do we gain the highest possible standard of living for the most people within whatever constraints the universe throws at us? Highest here being measured by what actual people think best maximises their utility, by their preferences of what they value. Constraints being, well, everything. Physics just doesn’t work that way, or it does, being no different in the sense of constraining action than chemistry or known technology or human desires - constraints are constraints.

Programs executed through a vast state machinery don’t have a good track record at delivering that although of course hope springs, as ever, eternal that some day, with some plan or other, they will.

The solution will be, as it is with everything else, markets even if they need to be nudged or adjusted. Because that’s the system which does produce that maximisation of utility inside whatever constraints exist.

We can also add, and we should also add, that such centralised and clod-hopping state plans won’t in fact work. This is one of the strong messages from the Stern Review itself. Where it is noted that humans tend to do less of more expensive things, more of cheaper. This being just one of those human things. This is then linked to the insistence that state plans, the detailed direction of activity, are more expensive ways of dealing with climate change than markets suitably nudged and adjusted.

The implication of this, and it’s made explicit in that very Stern Review, being that if we adopt the expensive method, the state and planning, then we’ll do less climate change dealing with than if we used the cheaper, more efficient, method of nudged markets.

This then means that those who insist upon the Green New Deal aren’t, in fact, interested in dealing with climate change for that’s the way of doing less dealing with climate change. It is, instead, an excuse to impose their other plans upon us all.

Something that many of us have twigged already of course but worth pointing out once again.

Read More
Tim Ambler Tim Ambler

The Emperor’s Net-Zero Clothes

Boris Johnson’s praiseworthy wish to save the planet rests on two ambitions: the UK itself achieving the global goal of net-zero carbon by 2050 and that example inspiring the rest of the world to follow, or at least moving substantially in that direction. The first ambition relies on the British people believing it to be feasible and affordable even for the poorest. My colleagues, Professors Edwards (Oxford), Kelly (Cambridge) and I address those issues in a research paper published by this Institute today.

We discuss whether the government’s strategy is coherent and the numbers add up, then whether it is feasible and, as the government does not seem to know, what the costs might be and, fourthly, whether the achievement can be rescued by new technology.  The answers to those questions are “no”, “no”, “maybe £3trn (one and a half years of total UK GDP or over £8,000  per person)” and “only partly”.  If you doubt these conclusions, read the paper.

This blog addresses why such a manifestly unrealistic ambition commands such widespread acceptance in the UK and who will be the little boy next door, following the fable, who will shout “the emperor’s got zero clothes.” It concludes with addressing the second ambition, namely that the rest of the world will follow the example of a piffling little country which is responsible for a mere 1% of the problem and cannot even command the support of its European neighbours. Or the Eurovision voters come to that.

The evidence for CO2 and methane rising is clear. Most of the public thinks that it is the cause of rising sea levels, floods and droughts and therefore, as with any threat to our way of life, the public holds government responsible for doing something about it. No one else can.  “Doomsday” as the Prime Minister called it at COP26 can be forestalled if we all agree to take the medicine the government is devising: “we gave you vaccines for Covid and we can protect your grandchildren from the effects of climate change.” The medicine, renouncing fossil fuels and having less livestock breaking less wind, is disagreeable.  Almost all energy will have to be in the form of electricity supplied by new, green, means.  This will involve new science and technology, new green jobs for all at higher rates of pay.  In short, the medicine is being coated with so much sugar that swallowing it will be a pleasure.  These are the emperor’s net-zero clothes. 

The conspicuous absentee from the ranks of the great and good applauding the net-zero attire is the Chancellor.  When the Energy White Paper appeared last December, we were told to expect a paper from HM Treasury verifying the maths: none appeared.  When the Net Zero Strategy Paper appeared last month in time for COP26, HM Treasury did add a review but it was not the expected support. While Number 10 claimed that the transition meant millions of highly paid new jobs and lower energy bills, the Number 11 review was equivocal: in true Wykehamist fashion, each opinion was balanced by the opposite. While acknowledging the Number 10 claims, Number 11 saw serious economic damage, business leaving the UK and higher energy prices and taxes as being just as likely – the implication was more likely – in short, a rift.

Treasury inaction and actions threaten the transition, notably on nuclear. Renewables are volatile and, with the global warming we will have by 2050, increasingly so. That means the all-electric 2050 will need a “baseload” of up to 40% of total Grid demand. Without fossil fuels, that means nuclear.  Fossil fuels and biomass may contribute but we have yet to build a single carbon capture and storage plant and we do not know how effective future ones will be. The Treasury has been blocking new nuclear for over 20 years.  All existing ones are due to be decommissioned by 2035. That leaves Hinkley Point C as the UK’s only approved plant by 2050.  It is scheduled to produce about 1.3% of our electricity needs.  Some way from 40%. If Sizewell C is approved next spring, we will have 2.6%.

Advanced Modular Reactors (AMRs) are more efficient, faster to commission, more environmentally friendly and are being built in the USA, Canada and China.  It is a competitive market with at least half a dozen suppliers and you can get ten of them, producing the same amount of electricity as Hinkley Point C, for about a quarter of the price. To get to a 40% baseload, we would require 323, at a cost of £254bn, presumably from multiple suppliers for security. 

November last year saw a trace of enthusiasm with talk of investing “£385 million in an Advanced Nuclear Fund [research] for small modular reactors and advanced modular reactors. This is alongside £220 million for nuclear fusion.”  Nuclear fusion is very unlikely to be a commercial proposition in this century and the £385M is going on the wrong horse, namely outdated Generation II SMR plants (as used in submarines), not the Generation IV AMRs everyone else will be installing. SMR plants, uniquely, are built by Rolls Royce and therefore, in the mind of the Treasury, must be the best.  Lobbying works.  

In the corresponding announcement 11 months later, all that had disappeared: the focus was back on big plants. A decision on Sizewell C (only 12 years and counting) was described as “urgent” and the cancelled Wylfa equivalent was back in discussion. The Treasury has refused to purchase even one AMR, allegedly on the grounds that they are new and have never been tried in the UK. More probably, the manufacturers of large nuclear plants do not care for AMRs and are lobbying strongly against them.

Not only is HM Treasury blocking new electrical capacity, it is ensuring that consumers will be ripped off by high energy prices.  EDF is being compensated for delays and risks (for which it itself is responsible) by being allowed to charge the Grid prices well above market rates even though nuclear power produces cheap electricity.  One of the factors delaying Sizewell C is the Treasury’s wish to try out its new “regulated asset based model”.  This is a 2020s version of the Private Finance Initiative only worse: the consumer starts paying for the electricity 10 years or so before she actually gets any and the City makes a ton of money at public, i.e. the consumer’s, expense.  The reality is that government can borrow more cheaply than City slickers and the Treasury does not have to bulk up those rates with commercial administration costs and profit margins. Her Majesty’s Loyal Opposition spends so much time being Loyal, there is little left for Opposing such scandals.

Of course, the same thought applies to the Emperor’s net zero attire as a whole: if they shone too bright a light on the plans, the Opposition might be seen as climate deniers.

Being led down the right path for the wrong reasons is preferable to the right reasoning taking us down the wrong path.  That may justify the Emperor’s net zero attire but not the Treasury’s wrong-headed approach to nuclear.  On the other hand, (and no, I wasn’t at Winchester) the Treasury is surely right to seek to protect the economy and consumers’ pockets. Philip Davies MP is also correct in condemning the net-zero enthusiasts for taking the UK down a road the rest of the world does not take too.  Saving only our 1% of global emissions would be simply “futile” as he calls it.

This is a global problem and it has to be solved globally. Assuming that the UK has some sort of divine right to world leadership to save the world is the sort of vanity that cost Charles I his head. In fairness, however, COP26 is proving far more productive than the cynics expected but we must wait to see if pledges are turned into action. Our Chancellor’s attention-getting pledge of making listed companies annually report their greening progress looks to me like more trees having to be cut down. But then the Treasury was always creative when it comes to putting their hands in our pockets.

Calling together 200 world leaders of countries, most of whom with equally little, or even less, contribution to emissions, is just as daft.  The few major world emitters need to find the solutions and then the levers to get the necessary (which might not need to be much) acceptance from the rest. Key is to give far more thought to the optimal speed of transition.  China has set 2060 as their target date rather than 2050 and they may be right.

The Treasury is right that overall, but not in the case of AMRs, the UK needs to move at the speed of the convoy, not commit kamikaze.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

Good enough is, actually, good enough

We do, entirely, grasp the point being made about carbon border adjustments:

A powerful incentive for the developing world to get serious about climate change, or just protectionism dressed up in green clothing? Whatever it is, the concept of carbon border taxes, once a faintly whacky fringe idea, is fast going mainstream, threatening to rewrite the rules of global trade.

The UK Government seems determined to tax just about everything else, but you may be relieved to know it has no plans to tax meat. So said George Eustice, Secretary of State for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs, at the weekend, even though livestock farming is a big emitter of greenhouse gases and environmentalists would much rather we didn't practice it at all.

Yet the Government very much does have plans for a "carbon border tax", Mr Eustice said, or "carbon border adjustment mechanism" as it is otherwise known. Designing one that works is another matter; even Mr Eustice admitted that it was some years off.

If we are to have carbon taxes - which we are repeatedly told is the thing to deal with that climate change, if that part of the science is right - then border adjustments to deal with the offshoring of pollution make perfect sense. They’re also difficult.

And the thing is that good enough really is good enough.

If we lived in a static world where equity and justice were paramount in the distribution of production, consumption and emissions then sure, border adjust away. The thing is we don’t. This isn’t a static world in the slightest, it’s one with a continuing maelstrom of technological change.

It’s also one where the actual problem, climate change, depends upon pushing technological change into a certain direction - toward non-emittive techs. Once these exist at economic prices then the problem is largely over.

Yes, OK, coal plants are bad but there are very few indeed who think that solar won’t be cheaper in 20 or 40 years time. Or nuclear, or fusion, or whatever. Steel from coal fired blast furnaces will be replaced, in that two to four decades, by direct reduced iron using green hydrogen.

Or rather, as long as the rich nations who do near all of the technological development in this world are pushed into favouring those low to non-emittive technologies then they will be developed. Once they have been developed and are economic then they’re something like a public good, something that can be and will be adopted by others.

A system that was perfect probably would include those carbon border adjustments. One without it will still be good enough as we still will have the incentives to develop the techs that make a mockery of the problem under discussion. Our suggestion at this point would be to leave it be.

Agreed, this is in part coloured by our general suspicion of governmental ability to do complicated and difficult things but rather more by the insistence that it’s just not necessary. Good enough for government work is a real thing after all. We care much less about the perfection of any carbon emission management system than we do getting there with the least effort and fewest mistakes along the way.

Read More
Your subscription could not be saved. Please try again.
Your subscription has been successful.

Blogs by email