Madsen Pirie Madsen Pirie

Queen Elizabeth- the one constant in a changing world

During a history class in my first year at a state grammar school, the imposing headmaster, Colonel Thomas, swept in wearing his gown and mortar board. He announced to the class, “I think you should know that at six o’clock this morning, His Majesty King George VI passed away. I think we should all rise for a minute’s silence.” We duly did so, and Colonel Thomas left us. As we sat down, one boy asked the teacher, “Please Sir, who’s dead?”

For the next 70 turbulent and changing years, his successor, Queen Elizabeth II, was the one constant that kept the nation united when it faced different challenges and new opportunities. It was under her first prime minister, Winston Churchill, that many of the wartime restrictions were abolished, including rationing and identity cards. I remember the glee with which I threw away my hated rationing books, though I kept my ID card for years as a souvenir.

After the Suez crisis of 1956, the country realised that it was no longer powerful enough to exercise sway in the world without allies. We used to tune in to half-hourly news bulletins and the BBC, then the monopoly radio broadcaster, introduced them for the first time to cover the crisis. 

The Queen then presided over a remarkable shift away from a British Empire and into a diverse Commonwealth of Nations which cooperated together to achieve joint objectives. It said much for the nation and its monarch that this was one of the few empires in history which achieved its dissolution largely peacefully. Queen Elizabeth was very much the cement that held the Commonwealth together. She valued her role as its head and exercised her influence to have it as far as possible share common values. I kept my school geography book that showed large parts of the world coloured pink, memories of a bygone age.

The monarchy was one of the few bright spots in Britain’s long slow decline into the economic chaos of the 1960s and 70s. The country sought to halt this decline by joining the European Economic Community, which it saw as a free trade area. The Queen visited many of the European capitals and leaders, and became a very popular figure on the European continent. 

Queen Elizabeth had an easy relationship with most of her 15 Prime Ministers, including Margaret Thatcher, the one who overturned the postwar consensus, and turned Britain around from being the sick man of Europe into being one its powerful and leading members. The retaking of the Falklands after the Argentinian seizure gave the nation a new feeling of self-confidence. I was in Covent Garden when I saw on a TV screen in a shop window that the Union Jack was now flying over Port Stanley. The Queen was now at the head of a nation that felt it had a new role defending freedom and democracy, and which was prepared to commit resources to that end.

The Queen presided over the dismal years of the 1970s when trade union leaders seemed to exercise more power than the monarch, or, indeed, Parliament. That ceased when Mrs Thatcher brought the unions within the law, so they were now subject to the rule of the Queen in Parliament. I still have the portable gas cooker and gas lamp that I used during the power cuts to which we were subjected by the union bosses.

Throughout her reign, the Queen took a delicate apolitical stance, wishing to be seen to not be interfering in politics. This was a major factor in having the whole country unite behind her, regardless of any individual views they might hold. Twice she gave a discrete but delicate nudge that may have indicated her own position. Just before the Scottish referendum on independence, she said that she hoped the people “would think carefully” before they voted. 

Just before the Brexit referendum, the Sun newspaper ran a story provided by someone at a private dinner party attended by the Queen that she had allegedly expressed support for Britain regaining its independence. The Palace, as usual, declined to comment on such matters. Having seen the United Kingdom enter into the European Economic Community some 40 years earlier, she now presided over its departure from the European Union.

She intervened personally during the Covid pandemic with a speech to the nation, reminding her subjects that normality would return, and that in the wartime words of Vera Lynn, ‘We will meet again.’ I took the vaccines at the first possible opportunity, and welcomed and agreed with her reassurances. 

I saw the Queen many times, but only met her once to shake hands and talk briefly. It was when I was an Edinburgh councillor and we held a civic reception for her, Prince Philip, the now King Charles and Princess Anne. She admired my Edinburgh graduate tie, and we all talked briefly about university life since Charles had also just graduated.

The nation must now move into an unknown and uncertain future, without the bedrock of stability that she offered during her reign of 70 years in which the modern world took shape. I was present throughout those years and the changes they brought. She was the one constant factor throughout them, bringing an aura of calm and stability to sometimes chaotic times. She will be sadly missed, but remembered with much affection and appreciation. 

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

Can we just remind, again, that prices do work?

Demands that the government must do something:

UK must insulate homes or face a worse energy crisis in 2023, say experts

Cutting heat loss from houses will be more effective in the long term than subsidising bills, according to analysis

The report itself:

An area that could make a real difference, but was entirely absent in the prime minister’s plan, would be tackling the UK’s energy efficiency problem. The UK’s homes and buildings are among the least efficient in Europe, which is making the crisis especially painful for households and businesses. Yet remarkably the Johnson government and now seemingly the Truss government have ignored this so far in their responses. The case for action is even stronger now that the government will be taking such large energy costs directly on to its balance sheet.

We agree, up to a point. Better insulation will reduce heat loss, of course. We would point out that a great deal of this has already been done. For example, the vast majority of houses without cavity wall insulation are those without cavity walls to insulate.

But the point where we disagree - that the case for government action is stronger now. No, it isn’t, the case for government action is ended. Because we’ve already that solution to hand - prices.

It is not true that if something needs to be done then government must do it. It is true that if something must be done then the incentives to do it must be properly aligned. So, the nation faces possibly bankrupting energy bills now and in the near future. They’re faced household by household too. Which means that every household in the country now has the finest incentive possible to find out about - and do - whatever insulation is possible.

We don’t need a government plan simply because we’ve already got a plan. Those prices work because prices do work. If soaring energy bills hitting wallet by wallet don’t incentivise people to insulate the loft - those few who haven’t done that already - then nothing will. It’s precisely because energy bills are soaring that we don’t need any more or other government plan.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

We must be socialist so that we can be poor

Another entrant in that race to explain why we must stop having a successful economic system and move over to one that doesn’t work:

The climate crisis will spiral out of control unless the world applies “emergency brakes” to capitalism and devises a “new way of living”, according to a Japanese academic whose book on Marxism and the environment has become a surprise bestseller.

The message from Kohei Saito, an associate professor at Tokyo University, is simple: capitalism’s demand for unlimited profits is destroying the planet and only “degrowth” can repair the damage by slowing down social production and sharing wealth.

There’s a logical hole here - it’s entirely possible to have a static and capitalist society. Most of history was just that after all. It’s markets, free markets, which produce the growth. So, to stop the growth you need to stop the markets, not the capitalism. Stop people trying new ways of doing things and you do indeed stop that growth - for growth is new ways of doing things.

There’s also an incentives mistake here. The demand for growth isn’t driven by capitalist demand for profit at all. It’s driven by consumer demand for a better life. It’s us out here who rather like getting more for less of our sweat by hand or brain. Thus it’s us driving that desire for growth.

Finally there’s a simple factual mistake. Back when the IPCC started modelling the global economy, in the Special Report on Emissions Scenarios, it was made very obvious that a free market and capitalist world solved climate change better than a planned and social democratic one, let alone a socialist.

So there’s not a great deal of either logical or factual support for this idea that we must all be poorer. Nor that we should all be socialist.

Back a century the great claim of scientific socialism was that by replacing all that chaos and waste of markets with proper planning then we’d be richer. That was why we should be socialist, to be that richer. Didn’t work out that way as we know. So, now we’ve this demand that we must all be socialist so that we can be poorer. We must still be socialist, it’s the justification that has changed.

Still, at least this is better than Jason Hickel’s latest demand - we should be poorer so that we can be socialist.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

Of course fracking will work

The Guardian runs just one of many articles insisting that fracking will not work in Britain. The geology is wrong, it won’t change prices anyway, how dare they and that’s the end of that. We take a more cynical - as always, when viewing politics, we suggest “realist” is the correct description of unbridled cynicism - view of the matter. If fracking really won’t work in Britain then the effort to ban it on those spurious quake grounds would never have been attempted. It is precisely that insistence that it cannot be allowed which convinces us that it will work if it is allowed.

As to price, yes of course increasing supply will reduce prices. By how much is the question and that depends upon the capacity of the infrastructure to feed it out into wider markets. The more that can be exported the less influence there will be on the domestic price.

But leaving the issue there is a logical failure. For gas within the UK belongs to The Crown. Which means that the resource value, the royalties, flows to the government. So, assume that all fracked gas is exported for a moment - that means vast floods of cash into the Treasury from all those foreigners buying the gas. We will have achieved Monty Python’s tax nirvana, we are taxing foreigners living in foreign countries. As opposed to what happens now, which is that Britain’s use of gas imports enriches the Russian and Norwegian governments.

That is, even if fracking doesn’t change prices it still benefits us here - producing that river of money which can be used to pay for our own government.

There is that possibility that the geology is all wrong. But even then going fracking still does work. Because the universe is contrary and such assertions do in fact need to be tested. Possibly fracked wells will produce gas which we can use or sell to Johnny Foreigner - in which case we are better off. Or, perhaps the naysayers are correct, fracked wells will produce nothing but expensive holes in the ground. In which case we are still better off - now we know. Uncertainty is reduced and we can then stop the political fight and get on with adjusting to reality.

This, of course, being the important part of the “free” in “free market”. Folk get to try out whatever comes into their pretty little heads, free of restrictions by those who either insist it cannot work or would prefer it didn’t and that’s the way we find out what is technologically possible.

There simply is no way at all in which fracking will not work in this wider sense. Even if it never does produce gas we’ve still found that out - and at someone else’s expense to boot. For that’s the capitalism part of the system - Ineos, or Cuadrilla, or some others, carry the expense of drilling those holes. We’re not trying to allocate some limited amount of government or taxpayer resources. We’re simply telling the world’s assembled capitalists “Come on then, if you’re ‘ard enough” and then seeing what happens.

Other than those desperately hoping that it won’t work why wouldn’t we go ahead and do this?

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

It's necessary to really read some statements

Here, about more gas not lowering prices for example:

Producing more UK gas ‘won’t bring down prices’

Oh well, that settles it then. The Times has said so. No point in fracking now, is there?

Except read more carefully:

Maximising North Sea oil and gas production is crucial for security of supply, but it will have only a “limited” impact on prices, the industry’s lobby group has said.

That’s talking about North Sea production, not fracking. And no, the two will not be the same in their effects. For if they were then the American price of gas would not currently be below the European - which, of course, it is. What matters is the volume of gas produced as against the capacity of the pipelines to export it.

Full throttle fracking would overwhelm export ability so UK prices would be lower than the Continent - just as American are now. And why would North Sea producers want the price of what they can sell - North Sea gas being entirely substituitable with fracked gas - to decline domestically?

There’s also this:

Offshore Energies UK is backing wholesale power market reform that would prevent electricity from wind, solar and nuclear plants being sold at high prices set by gas-fired power plants. But it pushed back on the idea of reform to the gas market to cap the price of domestically produced gas and prevent it being sold at high prices set by the international market.

We bet they say that. For reducing the price of electricity from other sources will increase the price that must be paid for gas. High prices limit, reduce, demand. Lower prices for those alternative generation methods and, ineluctably, demand does not decrease. Raising the price of gas derived electricity, therefore gas itself. But, obviously, they also don’t want to be prevented from taking a higher international price if there is one.

It’s often necessary to work out who is saying it, not just what is being said. For only when we grasp the who - and therefore the why they’re saying it - can we fully grasp the detail of what is being said.

As Ms. Keeler said in one of those great insights into politics and human behaviour “Well, they would say that, wouldn’t they?”

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

Just wait until those future Net Zero pledges come in....

We think we can say, without being contradicted, that the varied energy plans leading to some hopeful Net Zero future have not, not exactly, turned out as most would wish. As, perhaps more controversially, we’ve been saying for many years now the heart of the problem is people trying to plan things. Exactly as the Stern Review said not to of course.

But within those plans has been a further grand mistake. There has been a lot of “We’ll not do this” and “We’ll ban that”, Fracking, coal, the bumbling over nuclear has been akin to a ban and so on. When the concentration should have been on making the mooted replacements so wondrously cheap that everyone switched to them by choice.

Or, as we’ve been known to say, create that better alternative and watch in wonder as people use it. Rather than banning the extant thing that works and hope that she’ll be right.

As we can see right now, she’ll not be right that way. We’ve banned extracting the domestic gas we have even while we have an electricity system - because of unreliables and no, more solar, more windmills, does not solve this problem - that depends upon gas. We’ve bumbled to closing most of the nuclear fleet without replacing it. We’ve banned the use of the coal the island floats upon. And it’s really, really, not working out right.

Which is something to worry about really. We are where we are of course but the fools have more of this in store for us. Take, just as one, the example of the ban on petrol and diesel cars in 2030. This is again to make the mistake - to ban the old and workable instead of developing the new and better and gazing in wonder at the voluntary switch. Given the time HS2 - which is itself a boondoggle but…. - is taking to swing into action we’re not going to have a go everywherre and everywhen public transport system by then. It’s already impossible to build anything in West London given the electricity grid constraints. The electric vehicle revolution just isn’t going to be ready by then. But we’re still to ban that old and workable without having either the efficient replacement nor the ability to use the inefficient one effectively.

This is not - as that Stern Review, Bill Nordhaus’ Nobel and just plain good common sense insist - the way to run a country. But, and aren’t we the lucky ones, that is the way the country’s being run. Ban what works and hope just isn’t the right way around - invent and perfect the new and leave markets be instead. Prompt with prices if you must but given what’s happening right now who is looking forward to more of these plans?

Read More
Eamonn Butler Eamonn Butler

The Scottish Parliament is asking the wrong questions about ferry provision

The Scottish Parliament is conducting what it calls a ‘major inquiry into current and future ferry provision in Scotland’. Yet the questions it poses to respondents suggest that the future will look very much like the past — an under-capitalised and over-subsidised monopoly operator managed by quangos a hundred and more miles away in Holyrood.

As an economist, and one who spends much of the year on the Isle of Arran, it’s obvious to me that to have any future at all, ferry operations must be reliable. If, like today, they are not, vital island industries such as tourism and Scotch whisky will suffer, investment in businesses and infrastructure will decline, capital will be written off, and the islands will gradually depopulate —modern Clearances driven not by landlords but by politicians. And ferries without customers won’t exactly have a future.

Spare capacity, in both vessels and harbours, is a major part of reliability. Services must continue to operate despite disruptions such as breakdowns, accidents, annual or unexpected surges in demand, and adverse weather conditions. But the current CalMac fleet is among the oldest and least reliable in Europe. Other operators, for example, run ferries with multiple engines so that vessels are still able to run on one and rotate others for maintenance. They design their vessels and ports to be generally interoperable, so that when bad weather, breakdowns, accidents or other disruptions occur, nearby ports are easily accessible, and vessels can be diverted from one route to another. They also maintain spare capacity so that gaps in the service, and annual or unexpected surges in demand, can be accommodated. Even with the £1bn promised for new vessels (if it ever appears), CalMac will still lack such essential spare capacity.

Even the layout of the larger CalMac ferries shocks an economist, with almost half the main decks devoted to cafes, restaurants and bars — space that cannot be repurposed in the event that extra passenger or car capacity is needed (say, when island festivals or Highland Games are on). Continental ferries instead have bars from which passengers collect food and drink, consuming it back in their seats, maximising flexibility.

Future-proof ferry services must be able to evolve and adapt to changing demand. Just as natural evolution rests on their being biodiversity, so we need a diversity of operators if ferries are to adapt and evolve. Or at least the threat of other operators coming in and taking business off the incumbent by serving customers better — what economists call a contestable market. Today, though, we have one operator, supported by state subsidies, making it impossible for any other potential providers to get a look in.

Monopolists and governments, of course, like things to be big. They talk about ‘economies of scale’ and bring on bigger and bigger vessels. But real economists know that there are diseconomies of scale too. Ever-larger vessels require one-off design, construction methods and technologies, rather than mass produced ones. Hence all the problems with the massive maritime monsters so far behind schedule and above budget in Ferguson’s shipyard. With smaller, more frequent ferries, the occasional missed or delayed departure is little problem; with gigantic, infrequent vessels, it is a huge nightmare. Just the sort of thing to put off customers like tourists, whose travel decisions are made on the margin, but who are vital to the island economies.

The Road Equivalent Tariff (RET) system has further stifled any prospect of innovative new service operators coming in. The subsidy goes to solely to CalMac, which naturally fights to stop anyone else getting it. And by ignoring the realities of geography, the subsidy provides no incentive for the incumbent to invest in new ways to deal with these realities — essential, again, if the ferries are to have any future at all.

Whatever the arguments for it, RET has other damaging results too. Below-cost pricing of vehicles brings more large vehicles (such as campervans), onto inadequate island roads; already loaded with mainland provisions, they make local shops unsustainable. As do islanders, for whom it is now cheap to take the car over to the mainland and load up.

A ferry system with a future would charge commercial rates, bringing cash into ferry services and making customer demand, not bureaucratic decisions, drive development. If subsidies are thought desirable, they should be paid to the people who need them, not to service providers. And why should the populations of inland areas pay higher taxes for ferries that they might never use anyway? But then, if we did have a diversity of operators, it is likely that innovators would develop pricing structures (such as off-peak concessions for islanders, hospital patients or pensions) that would benefit deserving groups anyway.

Economists hate monopolies, and state monopolies are even less customer-aware than private ones. Scotland’s ferries will only have a future if there is an open, contestable market in vessels and ports. Only that will systematically drive innovation, progress and the evolution of services to meet changing circumstances. Right now, we are doing everything to kill off that future.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

Invert the argument to understand it

It can be useful to invert an argument to examine it for holes. Here we’ve a critique of supply side economics. Which could - could - be usefully true and could also be simply a trotting out of well worn cliches. To test, invert and see if it makes sense:

From this, much else follows. Taxation (especially on the wealthy) comes to appear like an obstacle to innovation and productivity, seeing as it reduces the incentive of rich people and big businesses to put their money to work. The welfare state is accused of fostering “dependency”, reducing the incentive for people to go to work and take responsibility for themselves and their families. Above a certain level, income tax makes it pointless for workers to increase their hours or efforts, seeing as they won’t receive the full rewards. Regulation and “red tape” dissuade entrepreneurs from setting up businesses in the first place. By devaluing people’s savings, inflation punishes people for their success and reduces confidence in the system overall.

But we know that taxation - at some rate and level - reduces incentives. We know that from the taxation of the poor - that taper rate at the intersection of tax starting and benefits stopping is widely agreed to be too high to maximise incentives. Which also, neatly, disposes of that second assertion there.

Regulation which makes it more costly to innovate - or even do something - does indeed reduce innovation, or doing something. Humans do less of more expensive things, more of cheaper, that’s just how the species rolls. Inflation doesn’t devalue savings?

The inverse is ridiculous - therefore the original declaration itself is too.

There are still interesting things to say about supply side economics, of course. Even we wouldn’t say that it’s everything although we’d insist that it’s a necessary precondition for success, even if not a sufficient one.

But the implications are moral as much as economic, and this is where supply-siders encounter a paradox. On the one hand, this ideology assumes the existence of some invisible army of entrepreneurs and grafters, bubbling with ideas and determination, who are being restrained by socialists and regulators. This accounts for the bold patriotic optimism of neo-Thatcherites such as Truss. On the other, it is scornful about the population as it actually presents itself, consisting of lazy, badly educated petty criminals, with no capacity for delayed gratification or a hard day’s work. Sometimes, it is a mixture of the two: a society of people who want all of the pleasures of capitalism, with none of the pain.

No, that’s not in fact the supply side argument at all. Rather, high taxation reduces the incentives to do something, high welfare reduces the incentives to do something, regulation increases the price of doing something. Therefore, a high welfare, high taxation, highly regulated economy will do less.

Nothing moral about it at all - it’s just an observation. Raise the costs and lower the benefits of doing something and less will be done. It’s not a difficult argument to follow, is it?

William Davies is a sociologist and political economist.

Ah, sociologist. They always do have a certain difficulty following economic arguments, don’t they?

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

No, we don't want national IP rules

A certain missing of the point of having markets and differences here:

The rules for academic spin-offs must change to inspire a British Google

We’re not in fact interested in there being a British Google in the first place. The value comes from being able to use, not from having created. So, where something is created matters not - it’s where it’s possible to use. But leave that obvious point aside.

In the UK, universities are free to set their own rules for what happens when a professor starts a company. The rules are administered by the TTO (Technology Transfer Office), three letters that, depending on the university, can strike fear into the heart of an enterprising academic.

A recent report from the Royal Academy of Engineers showed that universities are taking anywhere between zero and 60 per cent.

We agree that there are likely to be more spin offs where the academics keep more of the loot. But that’s not quite the point here.

But we need a national IP policy to allow universities to fulfil this potential, and to make sure that the British Google is as likely to come from Leeds as Cambridge.

No. For this is to miss what having different policies - we could even say a market in policies - does for us. Different people try different things, we see that some work and some don’t. People, logically enough, then do more of what works and less of what doesn’t.

A national policy on anything kills off that process.

The point being that yes, we do need the idiots doing the wrong thing in order to show what is the right. Leave it be - because exactly that failure of bad policy is a self-solving problem in a marketplace.

Read More
Eamonn Butler Eamonn Butler

Working hours are a matter for private companies

South Cambridgeshire Council (it had to be the other-worldly types) plans to be the first local authority in the UK to establish a four-day working week for its staff. Local ratepayers are hardly surprised. As an economist, however, I am both surprised and disappointed.

A six-month experiment with the four-day working week (led, of course, by Oxbridge academics) began in June. It covers only 3,300 employees in 70, mostly smaller, companies, and it is scheduled to run until the end of December. Many of those companies say they won’t be continuing the change after that: with people working different days, they are struggling with rotas and team management, and they realise that a four-day week suits some workers, but not others.

It is odd, therefore, that a large local authority should plan a permanent move to the idea, before even this slim experimental evidence is in. In Sweden, a reduction in working hours from 40 to 30 proved too costly to continue, which France discovered that four-days-a-week workers put in the same hours as before — but it cost more, since more of those hours were on overtime rates. True, there was the same boost to worker moral that has been found in most such experiments. But it was only temporary. As soon as people get used to the new hours, they seem no happier than they were before. The UK already has above-average job satisfaction, so it’s hard to justify changing things here.

Proponents say that four-day-weeks mean less employee absence, burnout and tiredness, though if people are working longer on they days they do work, maybe that will prove temporary too. And proponents say that a four-day week allows employees more flexibility: but flexible working and four-day working are not the same thing. 

Some jobs require a seven-day presence (in the case of councils, social work, perhaps) and other people (like Cambridge ratepayers) aren’t on four-day weeks. And while advocates say that four-day working brings a rise in productivity, you need a huge rise in productivity to maintain the same output. Again, we will see whether the effect lasts.

Critics argue that four-day weeks will be fine for better-paid, salaried workers, but a disappointment to those paid by the hour — potentially making inequality higher; and some workers, such as older employees, may struggle with the greater intensity of work demanded on the four days they do work. Additionally, the UK labour market is already tight, so it seems short-sighted to tighten it even further by reducing working hours.

It's interesting that worldwide, four-day working has expanded fastest in the food and drink and other retail sectors, where it might well make sense for workers in those sectors, who are often young and not looking for full-time work. The other sector where it has risen fastest are government, including education and utilities. That might be no surprise to taxpayers, who wonder if they are getting much value even out of five-day working. And anyway, should working hours not be a choice, negotiated between individual workers and employers, rather than something imposed by monopolistic state institutions?

Read More
Your subscription could not be saved. Please try again.
Your subscription has been successful.

Blogs by email